Environmental Engineering Reference
In-Depth Information
Renewable resources
To illustrate how environmental capital can be critical for determining trade patterns in
renewable resource industries, consider the example of
fi
sheries. As is well known, open
access
fi
sheries are vulnerable to depletion because of stock externalities. The
fi
sh stock
needs to be maintained at a healthy size so that it produces more
fi
sh for harvest in the
future. But in an open access
fi
shery, a
fi
sher who chooses to invest in the
fi
sh stock by
reducing his or her harvest rate will not reap the full bene
fi
ts of that investment because
the
sh will be available for others to catch. Hence theory predicts underinvestment in
conservation of the stock.
Now consider the analogue of the pollution haven hypothesis. Suppose there are two
countries, North and South. Assume that North has stringent conservation policy, and
that South's
fi
shery is open access. As in the pollution haven models discussed above, we
assume the countries are otherwise identical to highlight the role of conservation policy
in a
fi
ff
ecting trade patterns. Would we expect trade liberalization to shift
fi
shing e
ff
ort from
North to South and exacerbate the depletion of South's renewable resources?
Chichilnisky (1994) and Brander and Taylor (1997) studied this scenario. The result
depends on the strength of the demand for
fi
sh. If the demand for
fi
sh is low, so that the
fi
sh stock in South is just mildly depleted prior to trade, then the logic of the pollution
haven hypothesis applies. North's stringent conservation policy increases harvest costs,
and so South has a comparative advantage in
fi
shing. Trade liberalization causes South's
fi
shing industry to expand and puts increased pressure on its resource. Trade therefore
increases environmental degradation in South. Suppose, however, that the demand for
fi
sh
is high. In this case, South's
shing pressure prior to trade and
its stock will be severely depleted. Because of its depleted environmental capital (
fi
shery will have faced huge
fi
fi
sh
stock), its
sh harvest rates will be low. North, on
the other hand, with its stringent conservation policy, will have been able to maintain a
healthy
fi
shing costs will be relatively high and
fi
fi
sh stock despite the high demand for
fi
sh. Hence when trade opens, North's rel-
atively abundant environmental capital (
fi
sh stock) will give it a comparative advantage
in
shing. Hence in this case a pollution haven type of result does not obtain - it is the
high-regulation country that ends up exporting
fi
fi
sh.
Conclusion
Fears that trade liberalization will cause an exodus of polluting industry to poor coun-
tries with weak environmental policy appear to be unfounded. Although there is evidence
that stringent environmental policy does reduce competitiveness in industries intensive in
production-generated pollution, there is no evidence that it is the most important factor
a
ows.
That being said, there are still a number of channels via which pollution-intensive pro-
duction could shift from rich to poor countries. If pollution policy were to tighten up at
a faster rate in rich countries than in poor countries, then the competitiveness hypothesis
implies that we would expect to see a gradual relocation of polluting production to poorer
countries. Industries that are both polluting and intensive in the use of unskilled labor will
expand in developing countries as trade liberalization occurs: weak environmental policy
reinforces an already existing comparative advantage in such cases. And capital accumu-
lation in developing countries will stimulate the growth of capital-intensive polluting
industries.
ff
ecting trade and investment
fl
Search WWH ::




Custom Search