Information Technology Reference
In-Depth Information
=
u i (1, a i )
u i (0, a i )
+
s ij u j (1, a i )
u j (0, a i )
S
i +
j N
=
a j c i +
s ij a j .
(5.3)
P
i
S
i +
j N
j N
It is clear from ( 5.3 ) that no user participating is always a SNE. We therefore conclude
that at least one SNE exists.
Then we show an important property of the social group utility function. It follows
from ( 5.3 ) that
f i (1, a i )
f i (0, a i )
f i (1, a i )
f i (0, a i )
a j c i +
s ij a j
=
a j c i +
s ij a j
i
S
i +
i
S
i +
j N
j N
j N
j N
a j )
a j )
=
( a j
+
s ij ( a j
(5.4)
P
i
S
i
j N
j N
+
a
a i ,
Let a
denote element-wise inequality (i.e., a i
i
N
). The property
below follows from ( 5.4 ).
a i , then f i (1, a i )
Property 5.1 (Supermodularity)
If a i
f i (0, a i )
f i (1, a i )
f i (0, a i ).
Property 5.1 implies that if a user's best response strategy is to participate, then it
remains the best response strategy if more users participate; if a user's best response
strategy is to not participate, then it remains the best response strategy if less users
participate.
5.5
Computing Pareto-Optimal SNE
Next we turn our attention to finding a SNE with desirable system efficiency.
For the PCG for fully altruistic users (i.e., s ij
e ij
=
1,
N
S ), it is clear that the
social optimal profile a
is a SNE, which is the solution to the following problem:
maximize
a
a i
a j
c i
i N
P
i
j
N
subject to
a i ∈{
0, 1
}
,
i
N
.
(5.5)
Search WWH ::




Custom Search