Agriculture Reference
In-Depth Information
0 and the
feasible region is bounded by linear constraints. This implies that standard convex-
ity theorems can be used to prove that an optimal solution
The objective function G (
χ
) of Problem ( 8.22 ) is strictly convex if
χ>
χ always exists (see
Kokan and Khan 1967 ). Additionally, Bethel ( 1989 ) used the Kuhn Tucker theo-
rem to show that there are dual variables
ʻ v 0, such that the optimal solution to
Problem ( 8.22 )is
8
<
p
k h
if X
g
v ¼1 ʱ v a vh >
s
X
!
0
;
1 h H
q
g
v ¼1 ʱ v a vh
X
k h X v ʱ v a vh
H
ˇ h ¼
ð 8
:
23 Þ
:
h ¼1
1
otherwise
X
v ¼1 ʻ v and therefore X
g
g
v ¼1 ʱ
v ¼ ʻ v =
v ¼ 1.
where,
ʱ
The solution in Eq. ( 8.23 ) can only be used operationally if the normalized
Lagrange multipliers (
v ) are known. In the next sub-section, we describe an
algorithm for determining the optimal values,
ʱ
ʱ v .
If a solution is too expensive, it can be rescaled to suit the available budget using
a new optimal allocation that is constrained to being proportional to the original
solution. In this way,
ˇ h
and
the precision of the sample estimates can be directly
determined.
Moreover, from Eq. ( 8.23 ) we can easily calculate the shadow prices (the partial
derivatives of the cost function with respect to the right hand side of the variance
constraints
χð =∂
k h ). Therefore, we can use classic sensitivity analysis
methods to determine the cost reduction if one constraint is relaxed.
G
8.4.1 Computational Aspects
The multipurpose allocation problem outlined in the previous section can be solved
using either the Bethel (Bethel 1989 ) or Chromy (Chromy 1987 ) algorithms. These
algorithms are iterative procedures that converge to the optimal solution of Problem
( 8.23 ). We briefly summarize the two different algorithms in the following.
First, consider the Bethel algorithm. Let
ʴ vz ¼ 1if v ¼ z , and
ʴ vz ¼ 0 otherwise.
χ ðÞ be the vector of variables that has an h -th entry
Let
ˇ h ðÞ . This is calculated
t . For optimal
* and x * , we must
according to Eq. ( 8.23 ) for fixed
α ¼ ʱ 1
... ʱ g
α
χ α ðÞ ¼ χ . The following steps are used to find
χ .
have that
t ,
so the algorithm has an initial solution that is the well-known optimal solution of
the univariate case (Neyman 1934 ). Theoretically, every variable of interest in
ðÞ
v
1. For s ¼1,
ʱ
¼ ʴ v 1 , v ¼ 1,
...
, g . In practice,
ʱ ¼ 10
ð
...
0
...
0
Þ
Search WWH ::




Custom Search