Digital Signal Processing Reference
In-Depth Information
60
50
0.0003
40
0.0002
30
20
0.0001
10
0
0
300
1
300
1
0.75
0.75
200
200
0.5
0.5
100
100
0.25
0.25
0
0
0
0
3
1
0.1
2.5
0.01
0.001
2
0.0001
1.5
1e-05
1e-06
1
1e-07
1e-08
0.5
1e-09
0.1
0
300
1e-10
1
1
0.075
0.75
0.75
200
0.05
0.5
0.5
100
0.025
0.25
0.25
0
0
0
0
Fig. 15.2
More examples of risk premia. Conventions follow those of Fig. 15.1
against the mean-variance model's in which we let
I . The results are presented
in Figs. 15.1 and 15.2 . Notice that the mean-variance premium, which equals a
Σ =
/(
2 d
)
,
displays the simplest behavior (a linear plot, see upper-left in Fig. 15.1 ).
15.4 On-line Learning in the Mean-Divergence Model
As previously studied by [ 14 , 26 ] in the mean-variance model, our objective is now
to track “efficient” portfolios at the market level, where a portfolio is all the more effi-
cient as its associated risk premium ( 15.28 ) is reduced. Let us denote these portfolios
reference portfolios, and the sequence of their allocation matrices as: O 0 ,
O 1 ,...
.
The natural market allocation may also shift over time, and we denote
Θ 0 , Θ 1 ,...
the sequence of natural parameter matrices of the market. Naturally, we could sup-
pose that O t = Θ t ,
t , which would amount to tracking directly the natural market
allocation, but this setting would be too restrictive because it may be easier to track
some O t close to
Θ t does not have ( e.g. spar-
sity). Finally, we measure risk premia for references with the same risk aversion
parameter a as for the investor's.
Θ t but having specific properties that
Search WWH ::




Custom Search