Information Technology Reference
In-Depth Information
4.5 Extensions of the Black-Scholes Model
We end this chapter by considering two extensions of the Black-Scholes model
d S t =
rS t d t
+
σS t d W t ,S 0 =
s
0 .
In the constant elasticity of variance (CEV) model, σS t is replaced by σS t for some
0 <ρ< 1. Another possible extension is to replace the constant volatility σ by a
deterministic function σ(s) which leads to the so-called local volatility models.
4.5.1 CEV Model
Under a unique equivalent martingale measure, the stock price dynamics are given
by
σS t
d S t =
rS t d t
+
d W t , 0 =
s
0 ,
(4.17)
where ρ is the elasticity of variance . We assume 0 <ρ< 1. Under this condition,
the point 0 is an attainable state. As soon as S
0, we keep S equal to zero, with
the resulting process still satisfying ( 4.17 ). Note that ( 4.17 )isoftheform(1.2)but
with σ(t,s)
=
σs ρ , non-Lipschitz. The transformation to log-price, x
log s , will
not allow removing the factor s ρ . A formal application of Theorem 4.1.4 yields that
the value V(t,s) of a European vanilla with payoff g is the solution of
=
=
CEV
ρ
t V + A
V rV =
0in J × R 0 ,
(4.18)
=
with the terminal condition V(T,s)
g(s) and generator
1
2 σ 2 s 2 ρ ss f(s)
CEV
ρ
(
A
f )(s)
=
+
rs∂ s f(s).
Note that for ρ
1, the CEV generator is the same as the BS generator. In ( 4.18 ),
we change to time-to-maturity t
=
T
t and localize to a bounded domain G
:=
( 0 ,R) , R> 0. Thus, we consider
CEV v
t v
A
+
rv
=
0
in J
×
G,
(4.19)
v
=
0
on J
×{
R
}
,
v( 0 ,s)
=
g(s)
in G.
For the variational formulation of ( 4.19 ), we multiply the first equation in ( 4.19 )by
a test function w and integrate from s
R .Using s 2 ρ ss v
s (s 2 ρ s v)
=
0to s
=
=
2 ρs 2 ρ 1 s v , we find, upon integration by parts,
2 ρ
R
R
R
s 2 ρ s vw
s
=
R
s 2 ρ ss vw d s
s 2 ρ s v∂ s w d s
s 2 ρ 1 s vw d s
=−
+
0 .
s
=
0
0
0
C 0
The boundary terms vanish for w
(G) .
Search WWH ::




Custom Search