Information Technology Reference
In-Depth Information
the regulatory imposition of tariff structures that
prevented market-based adjustments. The hope
is that, in more competitive broadband markets,
the temptations to impose asymmetric retail tariff
obligations are less pressing.
In sum, therefore, the New Zealand case study
serves to further reinforce that asymmetric obli-
gations on an incumbent, be they embodied in
legislation, regulation or contract, do not create
a 'level playing field' on which competition can
play out. Whilst they may exclude the incumbent
from adopting some strategic options that might
otherwise be available, they open up the pos-
sibility of other strategic options to its entrant-
competitors that would not otherwise exist. The
ensuing interaction will not necessarily conform
to textbook patterns of behaviour or outcomes, and
will be contingent upon the emergence of other
exogenous factors (e.g. technologies) that affect
the balance of powers in the industry. Dynamic
competition is an inherently unbalanced game of
strategic interaction by parties each striving to
gain the upper hand. If asymmetric obligations
provide the opportunity, either party will utilise
the asymmetry to gain competitive advantage, as
has been evidenced in the case of New Zealand's
'Kiwi Share'. If legislation, regulation and con-
tract design fail to take account of the strategic
possibilities invoked, the outcomes may be very
different from those expected.
Boles de Boer, D., Enright, C., & Evans, L. (2000).
The performance of internet service provider (ISP)
markets of Australia and New Zealand. Info , 2 (5),
487-495. doi:10.1108/14636690010801672
Boles de Boer, D., & Evans, L. (1996). The
economic efficiency of telecommunications in
a deregulated market: The case of New Zea-
land. The Economic Record , 72 (216), 24-39.
doi:10.1111/j.1475-4932.1996.tb02606.x
Commerce Commission. (2003). Telecommunica-
tions Act 2001 Section 64 review and schedule
3 investigation into unbundling the local loop
network and the fixed public data network Final
Report. Wellington, New Zealand. Retrieved
from http://www.comcom.govt.nz/Industry
Regulation/Telecommunications/I nvestigations/
LocalLoopUnbundling/ContentFiles/Documents/
finalreport.PDF
Covec (2004). Benchmarking Telecom's UPC
service. Retrieved from http://www.comcom.
govt.nz//IndustryRegu lation/Telecommunica-
tions/Investigations/Unbundling-PartialCircuits/
ContentFiles/Documents/Final%20Draft%20
Report%20(August%204%202004)%20-%20
UPC%20Benchmarking.pdf).PDF
Dixit, A., & Nalebuff, B. (1991). Thinking strate-
gically: the competitive edge in business, politics
and everyday life . New York, London: W. W.
Norton & Company.
Economides, N., & White, L. (1995). Access and
interconnection pricing? How efficient is the “ef-
ficient component pricing rule”? Antitrust Bulletin ,
40 (3), 557-579.
REFERENCES
Armstrong, M. (2001). Access pricing, bypass
and universal service. The American Economic
Review , 91 (2), 297-301. doi:10.1257/aer.91.2.297
Enright, C. (2000). Strategic behaviour of internet
service providers in New Zealand and the perfor-
mance of this market. Unpublished paper based
on Masters thesis, New Zealand Institute for the
Study of Competition and Regulation, Wellington,
New Zealand. Retrieved from http://www.iscr.org.
nz/f240,4833 /4833_enright_210600.pdf
Blanchard, C. (1995). Telecommunications regu-
lation in New Zealand: light-handed regulation and
the Privy Council's judgement. Telecommunica-
tions Policy , 19 (6), 456-475. doi:10.1016/0308-
5961(95)00024-Z
Search WWH ::




Custom Search