Environmental Engineering Reference
In-Depth Information
2000). In this case the modeller is more interested in
understanding and representing system structure (and
its change) correctly - by considering what is essential
to system or agent behaviour versus what is the result of
historical conditions or path dependency - than making
accurate forecasts of the future. Indeed, if we are to
get anywhere near developing 'universal laws' for the
complex, adaptive systems that result from the behaviour
of humans and their decision-making, a focus on initial,
antecedent and exogenous conditions may be particularly
important (e.g. Ballinger, 2008).
The representation of a broader range of human
behaviours and decision-making contexts than has been
considered to date should be welcomed in future models
of human decision-making. However, as environmental
modellers we should remember that the ultimate reason
to represent human activity in our models is to improve
decision-making about environmental systems, not hin-
der it. Consequently, it may often be more appropriate
to aim for a model and model-building process that
can practically contribute to the decision-making pro-
cess rather than one that provides a mimetically accurate
reproduction of observed system behaviour (in the vain
hope that it will therefore do a good job of forecasting
the future). The development of a simple model that
focuses on facilitating communication between disparate
groups of experts or publics (like in companion modelling
presented above), may be far more useful for decision-
making purposes than a complex 'would-be world' that
proves incomprehensible. Uncertainty is central to the
human condition and to the outcomes of models of the
types we have discussed above and decision-makers are
used to making decisions the outcomes of which are
uncertain. Whilst models and representations of human-
decision making will inevitably be 'wrong' (see Chapter 2),
whether they are useful depends on how we apply them
and how well we communicate their assumptions and
inherent uncertainties.
An, L., Mertig, A.G. and Liu, J. (2003) Adolescents leaving parental
home: psychosocial correlates and implications for conserva-
tion. Population and Environment , 24 (5), 415-44.
An, L., Linderman, M., Qi, J. et al . (2005) Exploring complexity
in a human-environment system: an agent-based spatial model
for multidisciplinary and multiscale integration. Annals of the
Association of American Geographers , 95 , 54-79.
Anon. (2009) A model approach. Nature , 460 , 667.
Arthurs, W.B. (1994) Inductive reasoning and bounded rationality,
American Economic Review , 84 , 406-11.
Arthurs, W.B. (1999) Complexity and the economy. Science , 282 ,
107-9.
Axtell, R.L., Epstein, J.M., Dean, J.S. et al . (2002) Population
growth and collapse in a multiagent model of the Kayenta
Anasazi in Long House Valley, Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences of the United States of America , 99 , 7275-9.
Azar, C. and Schneider, S.H. (2002) Are the economic costs of
stabilising the atmosphere prohibitive? Ecological Economics , 42 ,
73-80.
Ballinger, C. (2008) Initial conditions and the 'open systems'
argument against laws of nature, Metaphysica , 9 , 17-31.
Boardman, J. (2001) Storms, floods and soil erosion on the South
Downs, East Sussex, autumn and winter 2000-01. Geography ,
86 , 346-55.
Bouchard, J.P. (2008) Economics needs a scientific revolution.
Nature , 445 , 1181.
Bousquet, F. and Le Page, C. (2004) Multi-agent simulations and
ecosystem management: a review. Ecological Modelling , 176 ,
313-32.
Cantor, R. and Yohe, G. (1998) Economic analysis, in Human
Choice and Climate Change (eds S. Rayner and E.L. Malone),
Batelle Press, Columbus OH, pp. 1-103.
Castella, J.C., Trung, T.N., Boissau, S. (2005) Participatory simula-
tion of land-use changes in the northern mountains of Vietnam:
the combined use of an agent-based model, a role-playing game,
and a geographic information system. Ecology and Society , 10
(1), 27.
Casti, J.L. (1996) Would-be Worlds , John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New
York.
Crutzen, P.J. (2002) Geology of mankind. Nature , 415 , 23.
Davidson, P. (2009) The Keynes Solution: The Path to Global
Economic Prosperity , Palgrave Macmillan, New York.
Demeritt, D. (2001) The construction of global warming and
the politics of science. Annals of the Association of American
Geographers , 91 (2), 307-37.
Epstein, J.M. and Axtell, R. (1996) Growing Artificial Societies:
Social Science from the Bottom Up , Brookings Institution Press,
Washington, DC.
Epstein, J.M. (2006) Generative Social Science: Studies in Agent-
based Computational Modelling , Princeton University Press,
Princeton, NJ.
Epstein, J.M. (2008) Why model? Journal of Artificial Soci-
eties and Social Simulation , 11 (4), 12, http://jasss.soc.surrey.
ac.uk/11/4/12.html (accessed 14 May 2012).
Epstein, J.M. (2009) Modelling to contain pandemics, Nature , 460 ,
687.
Farmer, J.D. and Foley, D. (2009) The economy needs agent-based
modelling. Nature , 460 , 685-86.
References
Alcamo, J., Leemans, R. and Kreileman, E. (eds) (1998) Global
Change Scenarios of the Twenty-first Century, Results from the
IMAGE 2.1 Model , Elsevier Science, Oxford.
An, L., Liu, J., Ouyang, Z., et al . (2001) Simulating demographic
and socioeconomic processes on household level and impli-
cations for giant panda habitats, Ecological Modelling , 140 ,
31-49.
An, L., Lupi, F., Liu, J. et al . (2002) Modelling the choice to
switch from fuelwood to electricity: Implications for giant panda
habitat conservation. Ecological Economics , 42 , 445-57.
Search WWH ::




Custom Search